Skip to main content

Capital Accumulation, Private Property, and Rising Inequality in China, 1978–2015, By Piketty, Thomas, Li Yang, and Gabriel Zucman

China has seen a large economic expansion after 1978. What is the distribution of the wealth accumulated through the economic expansion?

Piketty, Yang, and Zucman (2019, AER) provide the first piece of evidence on the wealth distribution between the public and private sectors, and top and bottom individuals. They find that the ratio of national wealth to national income has increased from 350 percent in 1978 to 700 percent in 2015. 

The share of public property in national wealth has declined from 70 percent in 1978 to 30 percent in 2015. More than 95 percent of the housing is now owned by private households, as compared to 50 percent in 1978. 30 percent of equities of the listed companies are owned by private Chinese entities, 60 percent to the government, and  10 percent to foreigners. "China has ceased to be communist, but is not entirely capitalists; it should rather be viewed as a mixed economy with strong public ownership. The share of public property in China today (30 percent) is higher than in the West during the mixed economy regime of the post-World War II decades (around 15 to 25 percent)."

On inequality among individuals, they find that top 10 percent income shares around 41 percent of total national income and top 1 percent income shares around 14 percent. The bottom 50 percent earns about 15 percent of total national income. As for comparisons, "China's inequality level used to be less than Europe's in the late 1970, while it is now approaching US levels" (higher than France, lower than US).

One interesting point not explored in the paper is what factors and mechanisms contribute to the observations. They argue (and provide a first-step analysis) that a combination of high saving rates, improvements in the legal system of property and therefore a gradual rise in relative asset prices can be the reasons. Formal analysis of the role of those elements will expand our knowledge on better understanding the growth path of China.

Regarding their measure of public and private sector shares, they only look at listed companies, probably due to data limitation. While listed companies are interesting per se, they tend to be more mature companies. For a relatively young and recently rapidly growing economy like China, a majority of players in the economy are non-listed startups and small companies. As the company age, size, business style, management operations, and industry distribution are quite different for those young and small companies than for the listed mature companies, we have reasons to believe the public versus private shares look different. For example, mature energy and resource companies, as relics from the purely public ownership period before 1978, are less likely to transform into heavily private-owned companies given their public good nature.  On the other hand, newly-established high-tech startups are privately owned in the beginning. Whether governments step into the late stage in those private-established companies is an empirical question to be studied.

Finally, can the rise in inequality be translated into worse well-being for the bottom population? One important dimension is the quality of consumption/wealth or the quality of inequality. It's also meaningful to look at the absolute value of the wealth of the bottom population. As they pointed out, while "in both China and the United States, growth accruing to the bottom 50 percent has been smaller than macro growth", "the key difference between China and the United States is that in China the bottom 50 percent has also benefited enormously from growth: its average income was multiplied by more 5 in real terms between 1978 and 2015." Although "China's inequality levels used to be close to Nordic countries" before the 1978 reform, it is a low-level income economy for the whole population. Whether the shrink in the share of wealth in the bottom population is inevitable as the economy grows is a question for future research.



Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Cultural and Institutional Bifurcation China and Europe Compared, by Avner Greif and Guido Tabellini, American Economic Review, 2010

How to explain the cultural and institutional bifurcations between China and Europe? In their paper Cultural and Institutional Bifurcation China and Europe Compared , Avner Greif and Guido Tabellini ( AER  2010 citation:187) demonstrated that initial distribution of values and social heterogeneity themselves alone could be the reason. Two otherwise identical societies can evolve along different self-reinforcing trajectories of both cultural traits and organizational forms. The collapse of the Chinese Han dynasty and the Roman Empire (after 220 CE) were turning points in the cultural and institutional evolution of China and Europe respectively. Large kinship organizations were common in the former but not the latter and this remarks the distinction in initial conditions. In China, the Han dynasty came to power while advocating Confucianism as an alternative to the Legalism of the previous Qin dynasty. Confucianism considers moral obligations among kin as the basis for social or...

China’s Gradualistic Economic Approach and Financial Markets (Brunnermeier, Sockin, Xiong, AER P&P, 2017)

"A key approach successfully employed by China to reform its economy in the past 30 years is the so-called "crossing the river by touching the stones" approach, a gradualistic method that optimizes policy through experimentation. The government will start with an initial (usually small) policy change, and gradually modify the policy based on the reaction from the economy to this change."  BUT, "Can China continue to use its gradualistic approach in the presence of active financial markets?" In  Brunnermeier, Sockin, Xiong, (AER P&P, 2017) , they provide the theoretical rationale for potential ineffectiveness of gradualistic policy approach with the existence of an active financial market. In align with the well-known time-inconsistency problem (Kydland and Prescott (1977) and Barro and Gordon (1983) ), incentives of front-run by private agents in expectation of ex post non commitment of the policymaker renders the gradualistic approach ineffective. ...

Challenges of China's economic system for economic theory, by Gregory C. Chow 1997 American Economic Review

Compared with the western world, China seems to be another world.  In his paper (AER, 1997, 124 citations), the most eminent Chinese American economist Gregory Chow summarized four types of differences: private versus public ownership of assets, Western legal system versus Eastern semiformal legal system, individualism versus the collective good, and multiparty versus one-party political systems . Does state ownership or collective ownership (owned by township or villages) predicts worse performance? Not necessarily. The successful experience in China challenges the dogma that only private enterprises can be efficient. As questioned by Milton Friedman, the statement that “most assets in China are publicly owned” is misleading. Though the asset such as land is publicly owned, the enterprise using the land is privately owned. The manager of the enterprise and the land is connected through “leases”, or known as “responsibility system”. Similarly, the government can lease a state ent...