Competition, Policy Burdens, and State-Owned Enterprise Reform, by Lin, Justin Yifu; Cai, Fang and Li, Zhou, The American Economic Review 1998
Started in late 1978, reform of state-owned
enterprises (SOE’s) is a long lasting cause in China. In the paper Competition,Policy Burdens, and State-Owned Enterprise Reform (AER P&P, 1998,681 citations), Lin, Cai and Li argue that the key for successful SOE reforms
is to create enough a sufficient level of market competition and remove the
policy burdens. In a less competitive world, the separation of ownership and
controls makes managers’ incentives incompatible with those of the state. Various
state-imposed policy burdens are often criticized to give a chance for
soft-budget constraints.
In 1996, SOE’s employed 57.4 percent of urban
workers and possessed 52.2 percent of total investment in industrial fixed
assets. However, over 40 percent of SOE’s are losing money. By definition, SOE’s
are owned by the state. However, the state needs to delegate their control
rights to the enterprises’ managers. The separation of ownership and control is
a common feature of any large modern corporation. Agency problems, such as the
moral hazard, private information and managerial slacks will arise. To overcome
the agency problems, at least in theory, the owners could monitor managers’
actions and base rewards on managerial efforts (Armen A. Alchian and Harrod
Demsetz, 1972). In practice, complete monitoring is almost impossible and hardly
incentive compatible. The cost could be prohibitively high. Free-rider problem
in large corporations make no right incentives for any individual or a group of
individuals (institutional investor) to monitor managers intensively.
The Soviet-type remedy for agency problems
is to deprive managers of their autonomy. The state provided all inputs to
SOE's for their production according to central plans and covered all their
costs. In turn, the SOE's delivered to the state all outputs and revenues. The
state set the wage rates of the SOE workers and managers. Irrational it may appear,
ambitions to mobilize a large sum of funds for heavy-industry projects in
less-developed, capital-scarce economy are the endogenous root. Although it did
succeed in building a few priority industries, the Soviet-type economy lacks of
technical and allocation efficiency (Lin et al., 1996). Agency problems are not
solved, but hidden away. Some problems, such as on-the-job consumption,
looting, and other wrongdoings were not serious in SOEs because of the absence
of managerial autonomy. Still, managers have no means to motivate the workers
and no incentives to improve their operations.
There is another possibility to mitigate
the agency problems: market competition. Some summary indicators in a
competitive market, such as relative profits of firms in the market, provide a
sufficient statistic condition for evaluating managers’ performance (Bengt
Holmstrom, 1982). The owners can design a managerial-compensation scheme that
is either directly based on the rank of the firm’s performance in the industry (Holmstrom,
1982) or indirectly uses a firm’s past performance in a competitive market as signals
about the managers’ talent and behavior (Eugene F. Fama, 1980).
Not studying the theory, but rather learning
from reality, the Chinese government initiated a series of incremental, gradual
reforms in 1979 that eventually resulted in a transition to a market economy. Initially,
the Chinese government allowed the SOE’s to share part of the performance
improvement by giving part (12 percent) of the increased profits or reduced
losses to the enterprises. The SOE’s could use the retained income for paying
bonuses to workers, supporting welfare programs, and investing in capacity
expansions. Gradually, the SOE’s were asked to deliver predetermined amounts of
revenue to the state and retained the residuals. Later, modern corporate system
was introduced. The state was entitled to the dividend on its shares in the SOE
assets. An unexpected effect of the above reforms was the entry and rapid
growth of nonstate enterprises, especially the township and village enterprises
(TVE’s) who benefited from release of previously strict limited access to key
raw materials, equipment and markets and a new stream of surpluses generated by
themselves in the reform for future investments. Nonstate enterprises faced
hard budget constraints and they would not survive if their performance were
poor. Sizable and health nonstate sector exerted a heavy pressure on the SOE’s
and triggered the state’s policy of deepening the SOE managerial reforms.
However, competition itself is not
sufficient for improving SOE’s efficiency. In fact, we observe that agency
problems in SOE’s were worsened after the reforms. Another crucial condition
for modern theory of firm (Fama 1980, Holmstrom 1982) to work is that firms
face common uncertainties. However, this is not the case with SOE’s in China
and other transitional economies. They bear a number of idiosyncratic policy burdens
resulting from i) insufficient comparative advantages in capital-intensive industries,
ii) retirement pensions, other social-welfare costs, and redundant workers and
iii) suppression in prices of outputs that serves for “livelihood projects” such
as energy and transportation. In theory, the state should be responsible only
for the SOE losses due to policy burdens. However, because of the
information-asymmetry problem, it is very hard for the state to distinguish
between the policy-induced losses and SOE’s own operational losses. This gives
rise to the so-called soft budget constraint problem. The state will account
for losses due to managerial discretion as well as policy burdens. This in turn
worsens the agency problems and invites more political interventions and policy
burdens. As long as the policy burdens remain, the soft budget constraints will
persist.
Whether state ownership or private
ownership is more efficient cannot be determined a priori. More important is to
have fair rules (competitive market) and a level play field (remove policy
burdens) for enterprises. After all, as the paper concludes,
Fundamentally, for any large modern corporation, as pointed out by Fama (1980), there are no owners in any meaningful sense.
Referees
Alchian, Armen A. and Demsetz, Harold.
"Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization." American
Economic Re view, December 1972, 62(5), pp. 777-95.
Fama, Eugene F. "Agency Problems and
the Theory of the Firm." Journal of Political Economy, April 1980,88(2),
pp. 288-307.
Hart, Oliver D. "The Market Mechanism as
an Incentive Scheme." Bell Journal of Economics, Autumn 1983, 14(2), pp.
366-82.
Holmstrom, Bengt. "Moral Hazard in
Teams." Bell Journal of Economics, Autunm 1982, 13(2), pp. 324-40.
Lin, Justin Yifu;
Cai, Fang and Li, Zhou. “Competition, Policy Burdens, and State-Owned
Enterprise Reform.” The American Economic Review,Vol. 88, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings
of the Hundred and Tenth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association
(May, 1998), pp. 422-427.
Lin, Justin Yifu; Cai, Fang and Li, Zhou.
The China miracle: Development strategy and economic reform. Hong Kong: Chinese
University Press, 1996.
Comments
Post a Comment