Skip to main content

China's State Enterprises: Public Goods, Externalities, and Coase, by Gary H. Jefferson, 1998, The American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings

One central theme in academic research about China is the existence of state ownership in enterprises. State owned enterprises (SOEs henceforth) not necessarily mean lower efficiency. Rather it depends on market structure. In his paper China's State Enterprises Public Goods, Externalities, and Coase (AER P&P, 1998, 99 citations), Gary H. Jefferson studied this question through the lens of Coase theorem (Ronald H Coase, 1960) and public goods.

It is clear that SOEs have negative externalities for the firm itself, the whole economy and non-state sector. The key insight of Coase theorem is the need of clear assignment of property rights and the elimination of transfer costs in order to create an efficient incentive structure. SEOs by definition (owned by all the people), lacks proper incentive structure to monitor the enterprises. SOEs is subject to opportunistic behavior of workers, managers, and local officials, such as stripping by managers, shirking by workers, predatory taxes, fees and bribes levied by local officials, and nonpecuniary benefits for employees and their relatives. A further moral hazard problem is created by the replenishments of SOEs from higher jurisdictions through either direct subsidies or the state banking loans. This could distort resource allocations and diverts investment funds and employment generating opportunities away from non-SOEs. Other theories, including  Armen A. Alchian and Harold Demsetz (1972) and Michael Jensen and William Meckling (1976),  support this “incentive view” of firm ownership structure. 

Will privatization help? How about hardening of the budget constraint (shut down replenishment)? Privatization is neither a necessary nor a sufficient condition. Without an efficient proper-rights market, there is no warrant that assets will be used in a more efficient way than owned publicly. This was the case with Russia’s voucherization. Hardening budget constraints is necessary but not sufficient. Without replenishment, consumption of the resource is rivalrous for small enterprises. This is the case with China's township and village enterprises (TVE), where self-assignment of property rights has evolved. Jefferson et al. (1998) show that China's TVE's generally do enjoy a more coherent set of property rights and more effective monitoring (enterprise autonomy, concentration of internal monitoring authority, and an effective incentive structure) than their state-enterprise counterparts. But large numbers of stakeholders of large public enterprises may not have the same incentives for self-initiate effective property-rights reform, who are more likely to face insurmountable free-rider and coordination difficulties.

The crux lies in an efficient property-rights market, implying costless information, search, entry and exits, transparency and ease of contracting. Once a world in which property rights are not clearly assigned and exchange is costly or impossible is transformed into a Coasian property-rights market in which rights are clearly assigned and transaction costs are low, the opportunity cost of state ownership becomes well defined. It is well defined in the sense that parties who employ assets more efficiently than existing owners will value them more highly and compensate existing public owners with the explicit price in the property-rights market. The remaining question is whether the total social value of the assets is completely captured by the explicit market price.

This is the exact situation in China, from a position in the late 1970s to the post reform stage. For example, approximately 150 municipal-based property-rights transaction centers were established throughout China, which plays an important role in merge and acquisition industry. Another example is decentralized assignment of property rights of SOEs to subnational jurisdictions, which plausibly combines public ownership with a vibrant property-rights market. The most successful outcome of the reform is reducing entry restrictions, representing a diverse technological and institutional mix of state, urban collective, township, village, foreign and domestic joint-venture, shareholding, cooperative, individual, and privately owned enterprises. 

The author summarized property-right markets with the following conclusion.
In China and elsewhere, emerging property-rights markets perform three functions: to motivate the efficient monitoring of industrial assets to avoid the "tragedy of the commons" and costly macroeconomic externalities; to mediate the restructuring and exit of unsuccessful enterprises, both public and private; and to select sustainable forms of corporate governance that are able to withstand mounting competition within the industrial systems of transition economies. China's emerging property-rights market has begun to perform these functions.

Reference
Alchian, Armen A. and Demsetz, Harold. "Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization." American Economic Re view, December 1972, 62(5), pp. 777- 95.
Coase, Ronald H. "The Problem of Social Cost." Journal of Law and Economics, October 1960, 3, pp. 1-44.
Jefferson, Gary H.; Lu, Mai and Zhao, John Z. Y. "Reforming Property Rights in Chinese Industry," in G. Jefferson and I. Singh, eds., Reform, ownership, and performance in Chinese industry. New York: Oxford University Press, 1998.
Jefferson, Gary H, “China's State Enterprises: Public Goods, Externalities, and Coase.” The American Economic Review, Vol. 88, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Hundred and Tenth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (May, 1998), pp. 428-432.
Jensen, Michael and Meckling, William. "Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and Ownership Structure." Journal of Financial Economics, October 1976, 3(4), pp. 306-60.

Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Dividends and expropriation, Faccio, Lang, and Young (2001 AER)

 The failures in East Asian corporate governance are blamed for the East Asian financial crisis.  In East Asia, the predominant form of ownership is control by a family, termed as "crony capitalism", and the top managers are often from the family. In  Faccio, Lang, and Young (2001 AER, citation 1861) , they document ownership and control structures among East Asian corporations and analyze the salient agency problem, namely the expropriation of outside shareholders by controlling shareholders, by looking at dividend behavior. To start with, they show an extraordinary concentration of control in East Asia, whereby 6 groups control more than 20% of the corporations in the 9 most advanced East Asian economies. This control is obscured behind layers of corporations, hence insulated against the forces of competition on less-then-transparent capital markets. However, family control is also predominant in West Europe, though the group sizes are smaller, with 5 groups control about

Cultural and Institutional Bifurcation China and Europe Compared, by Avner Greif and Guido Tabellini, American Economic Review, 2010

How to explain the cultural and institutional bifurcations between China and Europe? In their paper Cultural and Institutional Bifurcation China and Europe Compared , Avner Greif and Guido Tabellini ( AER  2010 citation:187) demonstrated that initial distribution of values and social heterogeneity themselves alone could be the reason. Two otherwise identical societies can evolve along different self-reinforcing trajectories of both cultural traits and organizational forms. The collapse of the Chinese Han dynasty and the Roman Empire (after 220 CE) were turning points in the cultural and institutional evolution of China and Europe respectively. Large kinship organizations were common in the former but not the latter and this remarks the distinction in initial conditions. In China, the Han dynasty came to power while advocating Confucianism as an alternative to the Legalism of the previous Qin dynasty. Confucianism considers moral obligations among kin as the basis for social order,

TFP Differences and Capital Misallocation in Developing Countries: Hsieh and Klenow (2009) and Virgiliu and Xu (2014)

Cross-country income differences for the most part reflect differences in total factor productivity (TFP) across countries. But what could explain the differences in TFP in different countries? Hsieh and Klenow (2009, QJE, citation 3021) , use establishment level data in manufacturing to measure TFP gaps between China and India and the U.S. They find that misallocation in labor and capital could explain 30%-60% of the TFP differences between developing and developed countries, which means that  China and India have low TFP mainly because that resources are not allocated in the most efficient way. Virgiliu and Xu (2014, AER, citation 571) extend the framework to study the role of financial frictions in determining TFP. They focus on one specific type of misallocation, distortion in capital allocation generated by financial frictions. However, they find that this type of misallocation explains only a small part, 5%- 10%, of the TFP differences. However, financial frictions reduces n